English / ქართული / русский /







Journal number 4 ∘ Tsotne Zhghenti
Institutional development versus Economic development in Georgia

Summary. Institutional development is an actual topic as developed as developing parts of the world. Institutional change process is more sensitive for developing economies. Georgia is post-transition developing economy with low incomes.
Twenty five years have completed after the collapse of the Soviet Union, but the economy of Georgia has not yet returned to the incomes level of the 90s. Besides successful institutional and economic reforms and years of high economic growth rates, GDP per capita in Georgia is lower than in other eastern European EU member countries. Post-Communist Georgia was characterized by both institutional and economic backwardness, while some post-Soviet economies have completed integration process into European economic and political structures.

Keywords: Institutional development, Economic development, Transition.

Introduction

After the dissolution of the Soviet Union, institutional problems faced to the Georgian economy divide into three main groups:

• To establish new institutions required for independent country (for example: The Central Bank and other governing bodies);
• The transformation/replace of existing institutions, institutions founded in planned economy need adaptation/modification in the market economy;
• To develop institutions to the level of institutions like developed economies.
It should be said that the first task was successfully solved and nowadays Georgia have successful independent economic institutions. The second issue is mostly solved, but problems still remains due to slow transformation of informal institutions. What can we said about third issue - over the past years Georgia have shown important institutional growth not only between other post-Communist European economies, but also the other developed countries. Still, there are still room for important institutional reforms, especially through global background of rapid institutional changes.

Body of the Paper

In our research we will use two institutional distinction (as individually as combined). First distinction is given this economist Douglas Cecil North - formal vs informal institutions. What are characteristics of formal or informal norms? Informal institutions defined by codes of conduct, norms of behavior and conventions. They come from socially transmitted information and are a part of heritage that we call a culture. Unlike informal one, formal institutions are written; they include political (and judicial) rules, from constitutions, to statue and common laws, to specific bylaws, and finally to individual contracts defines constraints, from general rules to particular specifications (North,1991). Other institutional distinction can be defined by not it is written or not, but about who is responsible for sanctioning when a rule has been reneged upon. Firstly, similar distinction was made by Ludwig Lachman in 1973 and it was answered question how institutions came about. (Lachman, 1973). German economist Stefan Voigt suggests two dimensional institutional structure (formal and informal, external and internal) where external and internal institutions are described as: if the state sanctions rule-breaking, the enforcement is external to society, if rule-breaking is sanctioned by members of society, institution is internal (Voigt, 2016).
Stefan Vogt offers a simultaneous use of both two approaches to get two-dimensional institutional structure. If we combine them, we have four groups (types) of institutions each with two institutional dimension. These groups are Formal internal (FI), Formal external (FE), Informal internal (II) and Informal external (IE). Sum of these institutions should give us total institutional space. By theoretical foundations of both distinction each institutional groups should be shortly described as:
Formal external institutions - laws and official regulations which is controlled by state.
Formal internal institutions- formal rules controlled by society and business groups.
Informal external institutions – public trust and effectiveness in state policies.
Informal Internal institutions – unwritten norms in the society, such as ethics.
Measurement of institutional groups indicated above is required several steps: find suitable indicators, sort and group them by their differences and then to calculate new scores. Measuring of institutions is one of the major problem in the institutional economics, because most of variables are not quantitative. Most suitable for this two dimensional model should be “Global Competiveness Index” which is provided by World Economic Forum on its “Global Competitiveness Report”. Global Competiveness Index include 12 pillar about competitiveness landscape of countries. Report use data about 140 economies and providing insight into the drivers of their productivity and prosperity.
From 12 pillars of indicators 1st pillar of index is interesting for our research only which name is “Institutions”. Pillar “Institutions” includes 7 sub-indexes and 21 indicators. Source of institutional indicators is executive opinion survey of World Economic Forum.
To sort and group indexes we must make attention to both dimension separately: institutions determined by index is characterized as formal institutions or informal ones? Who imposes sanctions? State (external institutions) or society (internal institutions)? Data from pillar A is used in our research. Pillar “Institutions” is grouped by A - Public Institutions and B - Private Institutions. Public institutions we can present as external type and private institutions as internal type.
Second dimension (formal vs informal) should be determine by specified characteristics of sub-indexes. To determine formal and informal institutions is used only sub-indexes, because every coefficients one sub-index belongs to same group of institutions. Scores for each type should be calculate as simple average of sub-indexes as they have equal weights in the total GCI index calculation.
Next step is to group GCI sub-indexes into the two dimensional matrix. Every type includes at least one sub-index. Coefficients in every group is listed above.
Formal external institutions:
• Property Rights (incl. coefficients: property rights, intellectual property protection);
• Public Sector Performance (Wastefulness of government spending, Burden of government regulation, Efficiency of legal framework in settling disputes, Efficiency of legal framework in challenging regulations, Transparency of government policymaking).
Informal external institutions:
• Ethics and Corruption (Diversion of public funds, Public trust in politicians, Irregular payments and bribes);
• Undue Influence (Judicial independence, Favoritism in decisions of government officials);
• Security (Business costs of terrorism, Business costs of crime and violence, Organized crime, Reliability of police services).
Formal internal institutions:
• Accountability (Strength of auditing and reporting standards, Efficacy of corporate boards, Protection of minority shareholders’ interests, Strength of investor protection).
Informal internal institutions:
• Corporate Ethics (Ethical behavior of firms).
In the 2016-2017 global competitiveness report, score of Georgia is 4.2 (1-7) and is ranked 66th among 140 countries. The score of the institutional index is higher - 4.4 (1-7), including indices -state institutions - 4.4 and private institutions - 4.3.
In order to assess institutional and economic deprivation, we compare institutional and economic indicators of Georgia to other post-communist republics in the region (Central and Eastern Europe): Albania, Armenia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Georgia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia , Moldova, Montenegro, Poland, Romania I., Russia, Serbia, Slovakia, Slovenia and Ukraine. In the subsequent part of the article this group is referred as “other post-communist countries”.


Figure 1: Economic vs Institutional level


Source: World Bank and World Economic Forum (2016)

Figure 1 contains economies arranged by two factor: global competitiveness institutional index and gross domestic product per capita (2016). There is a positive dependence between two variables across countries. However, Georgia has one of the highest institutional level rates, but there is a significant economic backwardness among most of other countries.
It is possible to calculate correlation coefficients between the two variables for country group in 2007-2016 years (Table 1). The strongest correlation between economic and institutional development was observed in 2007 - 0.81. In later years, correlation has been weakening through rapid institutional development of low income economies. Since 2012 coefficient is still growing. Correlation coefficient was 0.49 in 2016.


Table 1: Correlation coefficients between GDP per capita and GCI institutional index (pillar 1) in post-communist economies, (2007-2017)


Year 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Coefficient 0,81 0,65 0,59 0,46 0,31 0,29 0,32 0,37 0,46 0,49


Source: Authors calculations from World Bank and World Economic Forum (2016)

We also have calculated same coefficients between economic variables and institutional groups.
Correlation coefficients between GDP per capita and institutional groups (One-dimensional matrix, calculated by GCI indices):
Formal Institutions - 0.49
Informal Institutions - 0.49
External Institutions- 0.49
Internal Institutions -0.47
Correlation coefficients are almost same, because all indices is included in to two groups. But using more detailed two dimension distinction makes results different.
Correlation coefficients between GDP per capita and institutional groups (Two-dimensional matrix, calculated by GCI indices):
Formal External Institutions - 0.43
Formal Internal Institutions - 0.60
Informal External Institutions– 0.52
Informal Internal Institutions - 0.30

Economies with high economic development characterized by relatively strong formal internal institutions (0.60), while the least developed economies are incompatible with informal internal institutions as unwritten laws working in the society.
After assessing the relationship between economic and institutional factors, next step is to evaluate economic and institutional backwardness of the economy of Georgia compared to other post-communist countries. During the economic recession of the 1990s, Georgian economy decreased by 5 times in real prices (before 90s, Georgia was one of the wealthiest country in Soviet Union). To economic and institutional levels, economic development – GDP per capita, Institutional development – GCI institutional index. 1horizontal line – 100% corresponds average rates of all post-Communist European Countries for the relevant year. In 2007, the economic development of Georgia was only 26.6% of the above-mentioned countries (deep economic backwardness). In the last decade, Georgian economy was growing faster than the rest of countries. In 2016, the indicator was increased to 39.6%. As institutional side; level of institutional development of Georgia was almost equal to the level of average post-communist economies (98.7%) in 2007. After successful institutional reforms, Georgia became one of the institutional reformator in the post-communist world (indicator grew to 115.3%, 15 percent increase of index between 2007-2016).


Figure 2: Economic vs Institutional level (100% = Average of post-transition/post-communist Economies)



Source: Authors calculations from World Bank and World Economic Forum (2016)

Conclusion
It is clear that Georgia has successfully managed to eliminate backwardness for both - institutional and economic sides. Across rest of countries, informal internal institutions group has weakest dependence to economic growth. Between 2007-2016 years, institutional development level grew by 11.3 percentage point and economic development level by 13.0 percentage point compare to average of other post-communist economies. But, it is evident that incomes in Georgia is still low and rapid economic growth remains as a major economic challenge for country.

ACKNOLEDGMENTS
Research funded by Shota Rustaveli National Science Foundation (Grant number: PhD2016_135).

References

• ბალარჯიშვილი ი., 2008, „ინსტიტუციური ტრანსფორმაციის ბარიერული ხასიათი - ტრანსპლანტაცია თუ ევოლუცია“. თბილისი, ჟურნალი „ეკონომიკა და ბიზნესი“ #1 

• კაკულია ნ., 2009, პოსტკომუნისტური ტრანსფორმაციის ინსტიტუციონალური თავისებურებები და “ევოლუციური თეორია”. თბილისი. ჟურნ. “ეკონომიკა და ბიზნესი”, # 3, გვ. 37-46.
• პაპავა ვ., 1998. „პოსტკომუნისტური ტრანსფორმაციის ინსტიტუციური ანალიზი“. მეცნიერება და ტექნიკა, N 1-3.
• Bardhan, Pranab. "Institutions matter, but which ones?." Economics of transition 13, no. 3 (2005): 499-532.
• KASPERasper, W., and M. E. Streit. "Institutional economics: social order and public policy." (1999).
• Lachmann, Ludwig M. Macro-economic thinking and the market economy. London: Institute of economic affairs, 1973.
• Mitra, Pradeep, and Marcelo Selowsky, eds. Transition, the first ten years: Analysis and lessons for Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. World Bank Publications, 2002.
• North, Douglass Cecil. Structure and change in economic history. Norton, 1981
• North, Douglass C. "Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance." (1991).
• Voigt, Stefan. "How to Measure Informal Institutions." (2016), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2748214
• Voigt, Stefan. "How (not) to measure institutions." Journal of Institutional Economics 9, no. 01 (2013)
• Williamson, Claudia R. "Informal institutions rule: institutional arrangements and economic performance." Public Choice 139, no. 3-4 (2009): 371-387.
• World Economic Forum, 2015, The Global Competitiveness Report 2015–2016